The Dog That Did Not Bark: A Defense of Return Predictability
Cochrane, John H.
The Review of Financial Studies 21, no. 4 (2008): 1533-1575.
https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm046
“If returns really are not forecastable, then dividend growth must be forecastable in order to generate the observed variation in dividend-price ratios. We should see that forecastability. Yet, even looking 25 years out, there is not a shred of evidence that high market price dividend ratios are associated with higher subsequent dividend growth (Figure 7). Even if we convince ourselves that the return-forecasting evidence crystallized in Fama and French (1988) regressions is statistically insignificant, we still leave unanswered the challenge crystallized by Shiller (1981) volatility tests: If not dividend growth or expected returns, what does move prices?”
Seligman, Martin.
Annual Review of Medicine 23, no. 1 (1972): 407-412.
Glenberg, Arthur
Behavioral and Brain Sciences 20, no. 1 (1997): 41-50.
James, William
The Journal of Philosophy, Psychology and Scientific Methods 1, no. 18 (1904): 477-491
Haidt, Jonathan
Science 316, no. 5827 (2007): 998-1002
Haidt, Jonathan
Psychological Review 108, no. 4 (2001): 814
Schwartz, Daniel L.
Cognitive Psychology 38, no. 3 (1999): 433-464
Pinker, Steven
Studies in the Evolution of Language 3 (2003): 16-37
Loftus, Elizabeth F.
Learning & Memory 12, no. 4 (2005): 361-366
Loftus, Elizabeth F.
American Psychologist 48, no. 5 (1993): 518
Posner, Michael I.
Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology 32, no. 1 (1980): 3-25.
Tomasello, Michael, Malinda Carpenter, Josep Call, Tanya Behne, and Henrike Moll
Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28, no. 5 (2005): 675-691.
Tomasello, Michael, Ann C. Kruger, and Hilary H. Ratner
Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16, no. 3 (1993): 495-511
Minsky, Marvin
Cognitive Constraints on Communication, pp. 175-200. Springer, Dordrecht, 1980
Sloman, Steven A.
Psychological Bulletin 119, no. 1 (1996): 3
Seligman, Martin
Psychological Review 77, no. 5 (1970): 406.